Enrichment
The Economics of Superstars
12th September 2018
Rugby Union’s Premiership season is under way again. Yet another professional sport which operates on the principles of socialism: the money all ends up in the pockets of what we might call the “workers”.
In a sport which was allegedly only played by amateurs until the mid-1990s, earnings have boomed. The average salary in the Premiership is over £200,000, and the stars are paid around the million mark.
As a result of such payments, most of the Premiership clubs are only kept afloat by huge loans from their owners. Their accounts for 2016/17 were released at the end of August. Bruce Craig has put £18 million into Bath since 2010. Bristol owe more than £20 million. Wasps have liabilities approaching £50 million.
But the players’ earnings are mere shadows of those of the top American sports stars. According to Forbes magazine, in the year to June 2018, the 100 best-paid athletes made $3.8 billion between them. The boxer Floyd Mayweather topped the list with $285 million. Stars of popular culture pull in similarly staggering amounts. George Clooney earned $239 million and Dwayne Johnson was the second highest amongst male actors at a mere $119 million.
These vast sums appear to pose a challenge to economic theory. These players and actors are very good, but they are not so stupendously better than others who get paid very much less. How can this be explained?
The answer was provided in a brilliant article by the American economist Sherwin Rosen as long ago as 1981, entitled “The economics of superstars”.
Rosen based his theory on the fact that activities such as watching a sport or going to a film involve what economists call “joint consumption”.
If I am watching Arsenal, say, on the television, it does not matter how many other people are viewing at the same time. The game is still available for me to watch. In contrast, if I book a table at a popular restaurant or a particular seat on a flight, no-one else can use it.
In 1880, if you wanted to hear a particular singer, you had to go to a live performance. Perhaps a thousand people could enjoy the joint consumption of the product. In 1980, tens of millions could watch on television.
Rosen, writing well before the internet, argued that advances in communications technology such as radio and television increased enormously the potential size of markets involving joint consumption.
It is the combination of the joint consumption nature of these services and advances in communications which mean that a relatively small number of sellers can in principle service the entire market. And the more talented they are, the fewer still are needed.
For example, the football played in England’s Premier soccer league is in general better than that in the Scottish Premiership. But the English league rakes in well over £1 billion a year in television rights, and Scotland less than £20 million.
As Rosen put it so succinctly ““the possibility for talented persons to command both very large markets and very large incomes is apparent”.
You might also like
Human Development Index
Study Notes
Market Failure - Income and Wealth Inequality
Study Notes
Unemployment Policies - The UK Youth Contract
Study Notes
Wage Determination - the value of Fatherhood
25th April 2016
Beyond the Bike Unit 4 Revision Resources
23rd May 2016
Labour markets and Wage stagnation
6th September 2017
Getting to Equal in Mongolia's Labour Market
20th June 2018