In the News
Marshall’s insights into the benefits of agglomeration still hold true.
20th July 2020
Alfred Marshall created the idea of agglomeration economies. Are they at risk in many towns and cities as workers show reluctance to return to offices?
Paul Ormerod writes:
The preferences of the workforce are an important factor in the very slow pace of return. Fears expressed about the safety of public transport may or may not be genuine. It is certainly true that many prefer to avoid the time spent commuting and enjoy the extra leisure time this brings.
But why do offices cluster together in urban centres? It is easy to see that in the old days industries such as steel and coal clustered geographically. One was a key supplier of the other. Being near at hand minimised transport costs.
Offices span a wide range of diverse industries such as consulting, lawyers and oil companies. The reasons why they locate in close proximity are more subtle.
The views of economists on this are still shaped by the writings of Alfred Marshall. He established the faculty of economics at Cambridge in 1903 and was then probably the world’s leading economist.
Marshall described the tendency of businesses to cluster near each other as “agglomeration”. He gave three key reasons why this co-location is observed.
In addition to the savings on the costs of transporting the materials needed in industrial processes, Marshalldeveloped a theory of labour market pooling in which firms located near one another can share labour.
Further, he believed that “intellectual spillovers” were important. Firms locate near together in order to learn and speed up the process of innovation. Think of Silicon Valley, formed nearly a century after Marshall wrote.
A large number of detailed studies in recent decades confirm that these are not just mere theories. They have strong empirical support. The Harvard economist Ed Glaeser, for example calculated that in the US in the 2000s each of Marshall’s three reasons were of roughly equal importance.
There have been very distinct benefits to agglomeration. Throughout the developed world, the greater the density of employment in an area, the higher is its productivity. Head offices contain more highly skilled staff and so will be more productive than the average. But in city centres, their productivity is even higher than their skill levels suggest they should be.
Has Covid changed all this? More exactly, has the crisis enabled people to see that new technology could overturn two centuries of experience in urban centres in industrialised countries?
Certainly, offers such as LinkedIn offer the potential for efficient hiring of relevant skills and for employees to discover opportunities through their networks. But new recruits need to be integrated. And younger people probably still need a combination of social and remote interaction to develop their own professional networks.
It is less clear that remote working can encourage innovation in the same way. Much of the informal contacts needed for this cannot be captured by video conferences.
Yes, there will be an increase in working from home. But Marshall’s insights into the benefits of agglomeration still hold true.
You might also like
Lessons in Economics from the Nobel Laureates
26th September 2012
Can we escape the grip of secular stagnation?
9th March 2015
Archaic definition of child poverty needs to go
8th July 2015
Blind Cvs - Do Markets Solve the Problem of Discrimination?
2nd November 2015
Paul Collier on African Urbanisation
16th June 2016
200 Years On - How Relevant is Ricardo?
17th October 2016
Predatory Universities and A Level Grades
24th August 2017
Behavioural economics - much of psychology is built on sand
21st June 2018