In the News
Behavioural Economics has a Nobel Moment
12th October 2017
Behavioural economics has received the ultimate accolade. Richard Thaler of the University of Chicago Business School has been awarded the Nobel Prize in economics for his work in this area
Economics over the past 20 to 30 years has become far more empirical. Leading academic journals do still carry purely theoretical articles, but far less than they once did.
There are two ways in which this has happened. Major advances have taken place in the heavy duty statistical theory of analysing large scale data bases containing information on individuals and their decisions. This was recognised when James Heckman and Daniel McFadden were awarded the Nobel Prize in 2000.
Behavioural economics is much less technical. In any given situation, the decision which a purely rational person would take is identified. We then look how people actually behave, and see if there are any deviations from the rational way of doing things.
Perhaps the main finding of behavioural economics is so-called prospect theory, first set out nearly 40 years ago by Daniel Kahneman. In essence, prospect theory says that people dislike making losses more than they like making gains of the same amount.
Another important discovery is that when weighing up how to value costs and benefits which arise in the future, people often place much more weight on the present and very immediate future than standard economic theory assumes. In my column on 13 September I wrote about how this helps to explain the reluctance of electorates to deal with climate change.
These two results are backed by large amounts of evidence obtained in a range of different contexts.
So they are being integrated into economic theory.
But many economists are altogether less sure about much of the rest of behavioural economics.
One of the issues is that behavioural economics often gives the impression of being rather ad hoc. No reason is given as to why people in one situation appear to behave rationally, but in another they do not. Very few guidelines have emerged as to when we can expect to see deviations from rationality.
Another question is that many economists are prepared to accept that non-rational behaviour might be observed at a point in time. But in a reasonably stable situation, people will learn over time to be rational.
Behavioural economics is not simply about advancing scientific knowledge on the workings of the economy. Policymakers have become interested.
Cass Sunstein, Thaler’s colleague, served in the Obama administration as head of the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs. David Cameron set up the so-called “Nudge Unit” in the British government
Ten years ago, Thaler claimed that “nudge” could lead to “better investments for everyone, more savings for retirement, less obesity, more charitable giving, a cleaner planet, and an improved educational system”. In his 2016 book Misbehaving, he has backed off the extravagance of these claims.
Still, whatever the doubts and qualifications, behavioural economics has made a big impact. An economist can no longer be said to have a good training if he or she is not familiar with its main themes.
You might also like
Cost-Benefit Principle
Study Notes
Making the invisibles in the economy visible
27th June 2015
Blind Cvs - Do Markets Solve the Problem of Discrimination?
2nd November 2015
Anchoring (Behavioural Economics)
Study Notes
200 Years On - How Relevant is Ricardo?
17th October 2016
Are cash-rich companies holding back economic growth?
14th July 2017
Alternatives to Profit Maximisation Explained
Topic Videos